October 23, 2002
What's
In A Question?
Question:
what is the modern Tory definition of leadership? Answer: asking
a question. This at least was how William Hague told it over the
Euro. And I say this as someone who came to see a lot of merit in
him by the end this certainly was a man you could measure by the
stamp of his enemies. What so annoyed me was that he felt the only
way to settle party policy on the Euro was to hold an internal referendum
on it. Yet his ballot was a costly and unnecessary abdication of
leadership. How could one claim to be leading by asking other people
a question? Leading is telling, not asking. It was doubly pointless
given that all it served to do was very slightly reinforce the present
hopelessly vague policy. The only justification for a party leadership
having resort to internal party referenda is so as to establish
heresy. Mr Hague specifically ruled this out. So this ridiculous
vote didn't achieve the objective of 'stopping the feuding' as it
implied no sanction against Tory adherents of the Single Currency
project. When the time comes for the Blairite referendum, they,
we are told to this day, will be able without hindrance to campaign
against party policy, and for Labour policy (i.e. entry). Why does
this matter? Well only because such euro-peace as there is in the
party stems from the size of that infamous 61% victory in the leadership
election last year, and all that is draining away pretty quickly.
If
'unity comes from leading, not pleading' it was hard to see how
Mr Hague, in this instance, was. How on earth can a referendum be
seen as leading, especially one whose sacerdotal result once obtained
was not be used to whip the bare feet of Heseltine, Clarke et al?
Why did Tories have to be asked to tell the leadership that they
did indeed support the policy the then leadership had already decided
upon? This referendum was, of course, a fraud, as it didn't determine
policy, rather a weakling and indecisive leadership called it when
the big brother imprimateur of their astonishingly loyal and unquestioning
grassroots membership was required: it bore to democratic legitimacy
much the same regard that Saddam's rent-a-crowds do today. It is
instructive that even in the modernised Tory party there is no mechanism
whereby the newly empowered grassroots member can petition for a
referendum to be held on an aspect of party policy. Our internal
party referenda are wheeled out just as Tory opponents of real
referenda charge governments wheel them out in rigged fashion.
The
stated objective of this farce was to obtain a 'settled policy'
for the official Tory attitude to British accession to the Single
Currency. It wasn't about the rights and the wrongs of the single
currency, it certainly wasn't about whether or not the UK should
go in (that decision is the preserve of the government, not the
opposition). We deservedly have little chance of obtaining a settled
policy with such vacillating and indecisive leadership that needs
to enforce its policy by means of mob rule. But far more importantly,
the policy that resulted (and has endured to the present day) is
in itself an act of political weakness, and logical nonsense. It
is politically weak because all it amounts to is 'Wait and see:
Wait and see harder' (i.e. it is most certainly not the Single Currency
ruled out); and it is intellectually weak because why rule
out the Single Currency, now, at the next election, but leave it
at that? If the single currency, now, can be ruled out for the next
election, why only the next election? By the arguments Mr Hague
used and his mute successor, we assume, would use today 'we
have to rule it out for the next election as we don't know what
economic circumstances will be', the single currency could be ruled
out for ever as we have even less idea of what economic conditions
will be like the further we peer into the future.
Why
not rule the single currency out tout court, why this ridiculously
qualified one term edict, which only invites trouble? After all
ruling it out world without end would sort things out, but wouldn't
have any dangerous effect as no party could ever really be bound
by this if and when circumstances actually changed. Entirely predictably,
this 'historic ballot' didn't 'settle' the issue: quite the reverse,
the policy the referendum cemented institutionalises our factional
divisions.
To
justify this policy on the basis that we don't know now what circumstances
will be at the moment when Britain would have to enter the Euro
is insane (and a deceit). And let's leave to one side the fact that
a condition of political leadership/governance is that one has to
make decisions today on the basis of reasonable assumptions about
the future: in other words, it is quite possible now to make a judgement
on the whole single currency project and its intrinsic merits,
without running away from that by taking refuge in excuses like,
'I don't know what the exact, down to the last decimal point, economic
indices will be at the time'. Indeed, this is one of the biggest
flaws to the whole Hague/Duncan Smith approach it derives chiefly
from their mutual and successive unwillingness to actually make
a definite pronouncement on the Euro. Just as not being able to
know the future now rules out saying we will definitely enter, logic
suggests that that condition should also preclude ruling out
entry, which, er, it hasn't.
The
Hague line was, despite the propaganda at the time by Labour and
Tory leftists, not so very different from the derided Major-era
'Wait and See'. After all, all William Hague did was, wait and see,
and he has saw that, for the next election, and the next one
only (after all there are limits to how far a reasonable man
like Mr Hague can see) the Tories are against entry. Some vision.
In other words, this matter is not so patently and undeniably wrong,
like say Britain being abolished and turned into Euroregions, that
it could never, at some stage, be envisaged as Tory policy. Our
point of interest should be that, under our famed Masstricht rebel
of a leader, this is what persists as party policy today.
If
memory serves, the supposed genesis of this gambit (the referendum
to 'settle' policy) was nominally fear of some late 90s Conference
'revolt' planned by the Europhile left. Thus, in this battle, Mr
Hague provided leadership of Byngian stupidity and incompetence,
and deserved a similar fate. Their revolt (i.e. fringe meetings
to attract attention to their cause) was no more than Eurosceptics
did habitually, when well behaved, which was rarer than we care
to remember. To very dull, there is, as ever, a workable historical
precedent: after Bonar Law finally settled the great Tariff reform
decade long fight in favour of a TR solution (though likewise not
an ultra-TR-solution), the party, very quickly thereafter, was forced
by events to give up, as an irrelevance, this achievement, which
had once been the central goal of intra-right political activity
and thought. Anyway, that's as may be, and seems a very long way
from accounting why we're still in the election-losing business,
let alone why we lost merely the most recent one.
At
the time of the ballot, and under the screeching direction of most
Tory pundits, William Hague obediently trotted out the line that
the divisions over Europe were very important in losing the 1997
election. But this is a very vague account of how and why we lost
that contest. If it was simply the matter of the divisions that
lost us the last election then all Eurosceptics should have very
heavy hearts as it was sceptics who were the dissidents, unconstrained
by the electoral needs of the party e.g. the utterly pointless and
harmful Sykesian commitments in personal manifestos re monetary
union (as if it was necessary, as if we didn't know what these people
stood for, as if the absence of the commitment would have tied them
to the official line, and most importantly of all given the subject
of general elections and the winning thereof, as if it did either
the party as a whole or even Eurosceptics in particular any good).
Obviously
the way the great defeat of 1997 should be understood is not chiefly
through the medium of the divisions, but through the leadership
policies which caused those divisions. In other words the last Conservative
government was not driven out of office by a handful of nutty backbenchers
utterly defeated on their chosen field of battle, but by the personalities
of the big fat leaders (the Hurds, Heseltines, Clarkes and Majors),
and their policies. But then once we acknowledge this we
are left with grim consideration of the character issue: what one
might call the Portillo question. If the party was indeed heading
for defeat at the 1997 election because of the policies being pursued
by the inadequate incumbent leadership, why did the Portillos, or
the Howards, or for that matter, the Hagues, doubtless perceiving
these grievous defects in the party programme stay in the cabinet
(it was after all in their paladin hands, rather than peasant backbenchers,
that the power to change things lay)? What did staying on in office
do for them, their beliefs, their party, or their honour?
When
Leader Hague said that he wanted to put an end to the factions claiming
the affections of the party in favour of this or that pursuit, I
would have had more admiration for him if he admitted that his (correct)
solution was to lead one faction to victory.
Unity
comes from 'consistency, through clarity and through certainty'
we were told at the time. Mr Hague was a member of John Major's
cabinet and supported his policy (indeed from becoming a Tory MP
William Hague not once on anything challenged the party line, whatever
the party line was in all the tribulations and changes of the
last decade), yet his self-avowed claim to fame as Leader was that
his policy was so very different to that weak mess. This was doubtless
a goal to aim for, but on the Euro it was never one achieved.
Sovereignty
does not lie in the possession of an indigenous and exclusivist
currency; my objection over the Euro is not the idea of getting
rid of sterling, rather it is the existence of the EU, and the form
and direction of the EU. The danger in the Euro is the progenitor,
framework for, and purpose of the Euro i.e. the EU. Without an
EU an alternative to Sterling, or fixed exchange rates, or tying
the currency to Gold or whatever would have no qualms for me. In
that sense, I'm trying to be a cold and detached about this as possible:
the great problem, as far as I see it, is that regardless of the
result of any national referendum on the Euro, it still has the
capacity to rip an undisciplined party apart.
For
one weird minute, let's pretend that our policy going into the 2001
election deserved to be taken seriously: what would have happened
if, on this platform, the Tory party had won the last election,
and it becomes apparent that circumstances are 'right' for British
adherence to the Euro? We would hardly have stood for the entire
of this current parliament doing nothing, and waiting until the
next general election before getting a different mandate
(after all by then those pesky circumstances might have changed).
We would in reality have abandoned our ludicrous pledge. This, to
reiterate, is still party policy. It remains a reminder of
why we are not fit to govern.
|